1. What is our definition of "catastrophic climate change"? Does it unfold in a matter of seconds? What is the spatial distribution of this catastrophe? Is its impact uniformly distributed? Is this catastrophe predictable? How much time will there be between the diagnosis of "catastrophe" and the actual effects?
2. There are 7.3 billion people on the planet. The total land surface area of Earth is about 57,308,738 square miles, of which about 33% is desert and about 24% is mountainous. Subtracting this uninhabitable 57% (32,665,981 mi2) from the total land area leaves 24,642,757 square miles or 15.77 billion acres of habitable land. (source)
3. Hong Kong's population density is: 18,200 per square mile.
So, if the world urbanizes and lives in Hong Kong style cities, we will need 7.3 billion/18200 square miles of land = 401,000 square miles;
But there are 24.6 million square miles of possible land. So, our climate scientists would need to identify the 1.6% of the world that offers us the best quality of life under the new climate change conditions. Would life at this location truly be that horrible?
While I cannot answer that question, there are many different geographies and topographies to build our future cities. We have the technologies to protect us from floods, and heat waves. City design and individual choice provides many adaptation options. While I do not want to live in this world, this simple logic highlights the fallacy of even starting to talk about "catastrophic climate change" when we have so many spatial adaptation possibilities. Yes, there are adjustment costs but there are always adjustment costs. There is always a new generation of young people who have not locked in to a lifestyle.
The macro economists who write about climate change make a big mistake in not acknowledging the multiple sectors and self protection strategies that we have access to. Their 1 sector models of the economy assume away an almost infinite number of small ball adaptation strategies that each act to insure our future quality of life. Don't be lulled by this point that we should do nothing about carbon mitigation. That is not my point! Instead, economists have to think harder about the social cost of carbon in a world with many spatial possibilities and a growth of cities and urban competition. This is adaptation.
If this interest you, then read my 2010 book Climatopolis. For young urban and environmental economists searching for relevant research questions, I encourage you to work on this topic. Read my overview paper available here.
For those who interject that agriculture will supply no food, this doom and gloom is based on a geographic theory that no amount of ingenuity over crop choice or growing techniques can offset mother nature. Is that true? Our diet might change. Storage techniques might have to be improved. Transportation across large physical areas to connect farmers and the cities may have to take place to diversify spatial risk but this is globalization. Won't anticipated crisis create opportunities for those who can solve these problems? How resilient are farmers in the face of anticipated challenges? Even if the average farmer fails, what matters here is the best farmers. The best ideas will ultimately protect us from climate change. Economists need to revisit the models of CEO span and control but reconfigure the analysis to study agriculture.